This is my archive

bar

Call the Midwife Confronts Intrusive Government

You Will Respect My Authoritah! My wife and I are big fans of the PBS series “Call the Midwife.” She also gets a kick out of how teary-eyed I get watching some of the episodes. Season 12, Episode 4, which aired last Sunday on KQED, was no exception. Something else happened on it, though, that I found particularly interesting given the implicit position that the show takes on Britain’s expanded welfare state. We’re, of course, meant to believe that the National Health Service is great. Also, in various episodes, this or that nurse reminds a low-income Brit about various subsidies that are available for a wide range of services. So it was interesting that the latest episode dealt with one of the downsides of having centralized government control. There’s an outbreak of E. Coli in one of the facilities that the Nonnatus House runs and Dr. Turner and various nurses hop to it, moving quickly to quarantine the patients and nurses who are in there and to prevent other people from entering. Then someone from the London Board of Health shows up, and he is pissed. Here’s the dialogue, which takes place at around the 30:30 point: Threapwood: My name is Threapwood. I’m the new chairman of the [London] Board of Health. Doctor Turner: I informed the board, as soon as the outbreak [of E. coli] became apparent. Threapwood: You also “informed” us of the measures you’d be taking. That is not for you to do in a situation of this magnitude. Sister Julienne: Dr. Turner acted very swiftly. I, for one, was extremely grateful to him. Threapwood: And, as is so often the case, it is not the opinion of the Nonnatus House that matters. (Pause.) There’s nothing wrong with your policies, Turner. It’s the assumption of autonomy the board doesn’t care for. Note what he’s saying. Dr. Turner was wrong to do what he did so quickly, not because he made the wrong move, but because he assumed he could do it without consulting the Board. Turner had, in Hayekian terms, “local knowledge.” Of course, if he had consulted the Board, it would have taken at least a while for the Board to get back to him, which might have cost lives. (The little newborns were losing weight.) So what mattered to Threapwood (what a great name for a villain) was not saving lives, but losing control. This happens when you centralize power in government. I noticed something similar, by the way, in the U.S. government’s reaction to peace breaking out in the Middle East. Here’s Ron Paul, noting the U.S. government’s upset that peace is being achieved without the U.S. government’s input: Take, for example, the recent mending of relations between Saudi Arabia and formerly bitter adversaries Iran and Syria. A China-brokered deal between the Saudis and Iran has them re-establishing full diplomatic relations, with the foreign ministers of both countries meeting in Beijing last week. It is the highest level meeting between the two countries in seven years. Additionally, Riyadh is expected to invite Syria back into the Arab League and Syrian president Assad may attend the next Arab League summit. Syria was suspended from the Arab League 12 years ago when then-US allies in the Middle East signed on to Washington’s “Assad must go” policy that wreaked havoc across the region. And the nearly decade-long war in Yemen, which has devastated that population, appears to finally be ending, as Saudi Arabia is expected to announce an end to its US-backed war on that country. Troops from the United Arab Emirates are leaving Yemen and a Saudi delegation is arriving to negotiate a peace deal. [DRH note: That is no small deal; according to the UN, 150,000 people in Yemen have been killed by the war and another 227,000 have died due to the resulting famine.] To normal people the idea of peace breaking out in the Middle East is a wonderful thing. But Washington is anything but normal. President Biden dispatched his CIA Director, William Burns, to Saudi Arabia in a surprise visit last week. According to press reports, Burns was sent to express Washington’s surprise and frustration over the peace deals going through. Biden’s foreign policy team “has felt blindsided” by Saudi Arabia’s sudden move to get along with its neighbors.     (0 COMMENTS)

/ Learn More

Shen Yun and Advocacy

Captivated by their scintillating Internet marketing, I went to see Shen Yun, now branded “China before Communism”. Shen Yun is the theatrical enterprise of Falun Gong, apparently a rather profitable venture. Falun Gong is a controversial religious movement that is ostracized in mainland China and Shen Yun is controversial, too: see, for example, the New Yorker here. I wasn’t particularly excited. The show is divided into many, shorter bits. Some are rather interesting: I was enchanted by an Erhu soloist and found the singers pretty good. I thought the orchestra was excellent, and Shen Yun seems clearly capable of attracting great talent. They attracted great interest too; the theatre was packed, for a matinee in a mid-size Italian city, and most of the audience members were Italians, rather than Chinese expatriates. In the songs, a couple of verses were explicitly anti-evolution and anti-atheism, without much of an argument more than, “these things are bad for you.” Still, I don’t think many noticed at all. I was more puzzled by the rather naïve and cartoonish, dancing presentation of dramatic events such as protest repression and “organ harvesting”. I wish I could ask somebody from China if that kind of representation, which is necessarily euphemistic as it goes through dancing in beautiful costumes, resonates with her. To the Western eye, it doesn’t: it trivializes something very serious. However, the big criticism of Falun Gong is that this show is propaganda wrapped up in theater. I think that’s unfair. If this is propaganda, it is of the obvious, hence harmless, kind. The denunciation of communism is clear, but it is not overwhelming (it doesn’t touch any economic arguments, for example) and it can be ignored by the audience. In fact, I think most of the audience, in the case of the representation I attended, didn’t pay much attention and wasn’t nudged to. Plus, I can hardly see why this kind of “propaganda” should be a problem, in a world in which we are deafened by politically correct propaganda of the opposite time: which is not more subtle, but only more pressing. While my sympathies do not lie with the religious values of Falun Gong, I am appalled that such a show can be considered a “problem” by anybody. A last, bittersweet comment. Falun Gong could have gone for more religious preaching, or more political pamphleteering. Instead, they created a music show and achieved tremendous success. They understood something most of us libertarians don’t: that people respond to stories, not to arguments. Perhaps some creative minds in our movement should create a show, “America before socialism”, and tour the world and compete with Shen Yun. I bet it wouldn’t be the worst strategic move in the history of libertarianism. (0 COMMENTS)

/ Learn More

The COVID Emergency Powers Are Over

  Only 3 years too late. President Biden did something today that I approve of: signed a bipartisan bill to end the COVID emergency that President Trump had declared a little over 3 years ago. The bill passed the U.S. Senate by a vote of 68-23. Here’s a summary of the bill, Senate Joint Resolution 38: Resolved by the Senate and House of Representatives of the United States of America in Congress assembled, That, pursuant to section 202 of the National Emergencies Act (50 U.S.C. 1622), the national emergency declared by the finding of the President on March 13, 2020, in Proclamation 9994 (85 Fed. Reg. 15337) is hereby terminated. Actually, that’s not the summary. That’s the whole thing. Congratulations to Senator Roger Marshall (R-Kansas) for pushing this. It’s virtually always bad to give a President emergency powers. Here’s how Senators voted. 21 Democratic Senators and 2 Independents (King and Sinema) joined 45 Republicans in a Yes vote. No Republicans voted against but 4 Republicans (Barasso, Blackburn, Hagerty, and McConnell) refrained from voting. (0 COMMENTS)

/ Learn More

Diversity and Transgenderism in School Athletics

Further thinking has tweaked or clarified my opinions about social diversity. It should not be viewed as a fundamental value; it is simply a fact of life in any non-tribal society, and an instrumental value to solve otherwise insuperable problems of social interaction and to promote prosperity and human flourishing. Economics helps see this by providing tools to analyze individual choices and their social consequences. Consider the current issue of whether sport competitions involving women or girls should welcome biological males who identify as females. The Biden administration is proposing a regulation modifying Title IX of the Education Amendments of 1975. The Department of Education explains (note that “schools” include K-12, colleges, and universities): Under the proposed regulation, schools would not be permitted to adopt or apply a one-size-fits-all policy that categorically bans transgender students from participating on teams consistent with their gender identity. Instead, the Department’s approach would allow schools flexibility to develop team eligibility criteria that serve important educational objectives, such as ensuring fairness in competition. The Wall Street Journal paraphrases the Secretary of Education Miguel Cardona as opining that “every student should be able to participate in athletics, free from discrimination” (“Biden Administration Proposes New Rule for Transgender Athletes,” April 6, 2023) This is mumbo-jumbo. It is not possible that any student be free from discrimination whether he is a transgendered biological male wanting to compete against females, or she is a female who does not want not to compete against biological males. The “fairness” invoked by the government is really nothing else than what it itself decrees is “equal opportunity.” As emphasized by Anthony de Jasay’s theory of the state, the government “takes sides” among citizens (and individuals). In other words, the federal government decides against whom to discriminate and calls it non-discrimination. Note that imposing supposedly flexible rules is no less discriminatory; it merely opens the door to more arbitrary bullying from the top down. The (classical) liberal or libertarian approach is very different. Don’t ban or mandate, but let individuals and the organizations responsive to them adopt the formulas they want. Different formulas are likely to develop to match different preferences. Within budget constraints—the unavoidable scarcity of resources given individuals’ diversity and near-infinite desires—some biological females would participate in women-only sport competitions and others would make the opposite choice. It is to prevent this diversity, between states or schools, that the new regulation is proposed. We should not be misled by the government claiming that its regulation, as amended, opposes “one-size-fits-all policies”: it imposes such a uniform policy from the higher top down. It aims at replacing voluntary diversity by imposed diversity. That the state should treat all individuals equally cannot logically mean that that it must allow any of them to impose his preferences on others. In another post, I argued that a government can be non-discriminatory only by letting individuals make their own choices; see “Only One Way to Be ‘President of All Syldavians’.” With decentralized choices, delusions are less likely survive or thrive. It is a reality that men are physically stronger and generally perform better in sports. If the freedom of sport organizations and activities is recognized, it is likely that transgendered biological men would have to complete with men or in their own trans leagues, as most women would prefer competing among themselves. We must respect (peaceful) individual choices. Accepting physical reality or the social results of diverse individual choices is, of course, not bigotry. Individual liberty implies that anybody may identify to whatever he thinks best describes him as long as it does not involve violence or threat of violence, even under color of law. It also implies that anybody else may agree or not to change his own choices and actions because of somebody’s self-identification. The woman who married the Eiffel Tower in 2007 does not harm anybody else as long as she does not obtain a regulation forbidding others to “marry” the same object. (There is apparently some scientific basis for the recognition of “objectum sexuality“!) That the proposed federal regulation would only apply “to public K-12 schools, as well as colleges, universities, and other institutions that receive federal funding does” not defangs its discriminatory character, given the pervasive subsidization of education with taxpayers’ money. These decisions should be made as close as possible to the ultimate consumer of education. Individual choices should be preferred to collective choices, which are of course made by some government individuals or some majority and imposed to all. That the American left wants laws discriminating against non-transgendered women while the American right wants laws discriminating against transgendered men shows the common authoritarian streak of the two movements. In general, diversity is good only to the extent that individuals want it and are separately able to achieve it in a non-discriminatory political system. Outside such voluntary diversity, there most likely exists a minimum of ethics without which a society of equally free individuals becomes impossible. For James Buchanan, this ethics is a market-like ethics of reciprocity; for Friedrich Hayek, it lies in the respect of the abstract and impersonal order of a liberal society (see my forthcoming Econlib review of the third part of Hayek’s The Political Order of a Free People). (0 COMMENTS)

/ Learn More

COVID and Tradeoffs

My frequent co-author Charley Hooper, Stanford epidemiologist and economist Jay Bhattacharya, and I met for lunch in Palo Alto on Friday. See pic above. Not surprisingly, much of what we discussed was the ways in which Twitter, at the behest of various major players, tried to shut Jay down. He was so often accused of wanting to kill people and it seemed to be for at least one of the three reasons: (1) he pointed out that young children were at an extremely low risk from Covid and, therefore, there was little basis for shutting down schools; (2) he noted that so few economists were pointing out one of the most basic principles in economics–TANSTAAFL, which means there are tradeoffs; and (3) he reminded people that we do develop immunity to coronaviruses. If people, including Anthony Fauci and Francis Collins, hadn’t tried so hard to shut him down, just think how different the discussion might have gone. Fortunately, Jay’s head is, in the words of one of my two favorite poems, “Invictus” (which was also the favorite poem of Nelson Mandela), “bloody, but unbowed.” (0 COMMENTS)

/ Learn More

Daniel Gordis on Israel and Impossible Takes Longer

As Israel turns 75, has it fulfilled the promise of its founders? Daniel Gordis of Shalem College talks about his book, Impossible Takes Longer, with EconTalk’s Russ Roberts looking at the successes and failures of Israel. Topics discussed include the history of Zionism, the plight of the Palestinians, the Jewishness of the Jewish state, and […] The post Daniel Gordis on Israel and Impossible Takes Longer appeared first on Econlib.

/ Learn More

Profit margins and inflation

Some pundits argue that America’s recent inflation is caused by corporate price gouging. I find that claim to be rather implausible. Why would corporations suddenly choose to engage in price gouging in 2022? Why not 2017? Or 2012? So I decided to check the national income accounts. Here are the percentage changes from the 4th quarter of 2021 to the 4th quarter of 2022 (all nominal variables):National income: +6.8%Labor compensation: +7.1%Capital (and proprietor) income: +0.9%Corporate income: + 1.2%What am I missing? Why would this data lead people to believe that profit margins are the major factor driving inflation? (0 COMMENTS)

/ Learn More

Seeing the Invisible Hand

Adam Smith’s “invisible hand” is certainly the most wondrous, astounding and marvelous concept in all of economics, and there are quite a few doozies in the dismal science. I go further than that. The invisible hand ranks as high or higher, in terms of pure beauty, than even the smile of a baby, the music of Mozart, or the most beautiful sunset that ever took place. In terms of what it means for our potential prosperity, it has no upper bounds whatsoever. Bastiat perched on the top of the Eifel Tower, looked down at the people scurrying around far down below him, and marveled at the fact that Paris got fed, without any central direction at all. This was the invisible hand (that is, free enterprise) at work; you can’t see this “hand,” but you can discern its effects. We all marvel at the teamwork of the championship basketball team, the winner of the eight-person shell in the regatta, a 100-member orchestra playing 64th notes without a hair’s breath of discord. But this pales into total insignificance compared to the teamwork made at least potentially possible by the invisible hand; all eight billion of us cooperating producing goods and services and thus fighting poverty. These other accomplishments have a coach, a coxswain, or a conductor. In contrast, when the human race bans protectionism and regulation, the invisible hand will take over without any central direction at all. If that is not a miracle, then nothing is (Adam Smith thought that the invisible hand was God’s hand). If that does not at least slightly shake up the atheists of the world, then nothing will. The claim that “competition tends to bring about a better product” is also profound, and, also, part and parcel of the invisible hand. It explains, as if an explanation were necessary, the inefficiency of the post office and the motor vehicle bureau. Thomas Sowell said it best when he averred: “It is hard to imagine a more stupid or dangerous way of making decisions that by putting those decisions in the hands of people who pay no penalty for being wrong.” He, too, is channeling the invisible hand. The reason we have pretty good fast food, given the prices we must pay for it, is due to competition. McDonald’s, Burger King, Wendy’s, and all the other participants in this industry are continually trying to figure out better ways to satisfy customers, whether it is by shortening queues and thus wait times, or introducing newer and better products, or providing scrupulously clean restrooms (hey, they are only human, and we don’t pay all that much; lighten up, they do a pretty good job here too). Why? Profit seeking. I know this is a dirty word in some circles, but it is an honorable part and parcel of the invisible hand. What about when there are few competitors? Does the invisible hand still function? Consider the only restaurant, grocery store or bowling alley in Duckburg, USA, a village of 500 population located 100 miles away from the nearest city or even town. Can they give the middle finger to customers? Not if the invisible hand is still operating, and it operates everywhere. No, the proprietors of these establishments will still strive to earn profits and the only way they can attain this goal is by providing good products and service relative to the prices they charge. If they do not, Duckburgers will eat more meals at home, seek other forms of entertainment, or in the extreme move elsewhere. There is always the “danger” of new entrants arriving in the village; that is, potential competition counts too. Suppose bridges were privately owned (work with me here!). Establishment A was convenient, but dangerous. B was safe, but out of the way. Would the invisible hand function even in this example? You bet your boots it would. There are always motorists on the verge of patronizing the two. They can be knocked off the fence by A’s behavior. An improvement in safety of A would attract more paying customers, and garner more profits for the owner, provided, only, that the costs of so doing, all things considered, were lower than the value placed on this improvement by the marginal bridge user. Hint: don’t bet against the invisible hand. It is a losing proposition.   Walter E. Block is Harold E. Wirth Eminent Scholar Endowed Chair and Professor of Economics at Loyola University New Orleans and is co-author of the 2015 book Water Capitalism: The Case for Privatizing Oceans, Rivers, Lakes, and Aquifers. New York City, N.Y.: Lexington Books, Rowman and Littlefield (with Peter Lothian Nelson ). (2 COMMENTS)

/ Learn More

Cuba: A Monetary Phenomenon

To write about statistics and Cuba is, inevitably, to speak of oxymoronic terms. Whenever someone tries to approach the Cuban case from the lens of years prior to 1959, or even after, the stats are either obscure, non-transparent, or nonexistent. That is not to say that the work in this field does not exist. On the contrary, various third parties have tried to devise ways to analyze the Cuban case. Some of these individuals and organizations have been elToque, Steve Hanke, and Pedro Monreal. Yet, it is indispensable to make the clear and concise statement that even with these contributions, we still are behind the curve regarding information on the Cuban economy. On the side of the Cuban regime, the National Office of Statistics, commonly known in Spanish as “Oficina Nacional de Estadistica e Informacion” (ONEI), has done a choppy job of providing precise and transparent details that we can rely on, as has been pointed out by Diario de Cuba. Every statistic or graph you may see about the state of the finances of the Cuban state or its economy must be taken with a pinch of salt. The other day, I came across a graph Hanke posted on his Twitter timeline, stating that Cuba’s inflation was 81%. Such a number significantly impacted me. Since the pandemic is already over, reforms are on their way to shape a “private market,” and even remittances would start reopening. At this point, there was no excuse for the Cuban government not to control the inflationary pressures. The Economy Minister of Cuba, Dr. Alejandro Gil, has said numerous times that the leading cause of inflation in Cuba was a “national deficit in the supply of goods.” Although the wording of the reason is confusing, Gil is saying there are not enough products in the peso denomination to back up the notes the government has been emitting. In other words, a generalized scarcity provokes prices to soar. Nonetheless, this does not make any sense. In any “normal country,” the central bank or even the government would look to control inflation by decreasing output using monetary policy.   Monetary Theory in Action! Following this logic, I was excited to test Milton Friedman’s famous quote where he said: “Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon.” To clearly demonstrate this, I prepared a graph in the old, classy way Milton Friedman would do it. Although I took the M2 data from the ONEI, since there is no other alternative source to refer to, I used the GDP deflator from the World Bank for my inflation rate. Even though it seems awkward to today’s standard to use GDP deflator as a measure of inflation, it was the only measure I found that had provided data since the 1990s. The results are expressed in the graph below.   Source: Oficina Nacional de Estadistica e Informacion (2021) & World Bank (2021)   Even the most brute eye test would see that as the quantity of money increases, prices must also increase. As if it were necessary, I also did a correlation test that came up to approximately 0.91. The question that now arises is, why would the Cuban government debase its currency so heavily? The answer to this, as some may guess, is complicated. If we outline some of the reasons, we would definitely conclude that the economy has not recovered yet from Covid. Even after two years, the Cuban economy is taking time to get back on track. The evidence of this is that the GDP growth is still lower than before the pandemic. That might cause the public revenue to decline, forcing the government to spend more. Source:  Oficina Nacional de Estadistica e Informacion (2021)   Also, with inflationary pressures underway, the government increased the salaries of the public workers, which instead of helping, added more gasoline to the already burning fire. Rafaela Cruz, a Cuban economist, noted that these increases in wages would cause increases in the base money to meet these. Again, given a wrong diagnosis, it is not weird to expect an incorrect solution. Finally, a notable mention is that Cuba’s budget deficit is only comparable to what it had in the 1990s when the special period was taking place. In fact, last week I tweeted the graph below, showing the budget deficits as a percentage of GDP. Although these deficits may not explain the increases in the monetary bases altogether, it partially puts color into why the Cuban government has been printing money lately. As a last remark, we must remember that Cuba is involved in a court case that would determine whether Cuba would default on its debt. Source: Trading Economics (2021)   Conclusion The monetarists‘ premises still apply to today’s economies, showing how increases in base money would inevitably lead to price increases. The Cuban case is one of the many still to be studied and described to the public. Old monetary doctrines are no longer dead; they were never killed, just forgotten.   Carlos Martinez is a Cuban American undergraduate student attending Rockford University. He is pursuing a BS in financial economics. Currently, he holds an Associate of Arts degree in economics and data analysis. (0 COMMENTS)

/ Learn More

Progress on the Southern Border; Yes, Really

I read a lot of right-wing and conservative sites on the web and I often see the authors highlighting the huge number of illegal aliens crossing the southern border. What I rarely see is any of them noting progress, from their viewpoint, when it happens under Biden. That’s one of many reasons that the Cato Institute’s Alex Nowrasteh’s work is so valuable. He does careful empirical work to document what’s happening, On March 29, on Cato’s blog, Alex wrote a piece titled “Biden’s Border Immigration Policy Is Still Reducing Border Crossings and Illegal Immigration.” An excerpt: From December 2022 to February 2023, encounters of migrants crossing the southwest (SW) border with Mexico are down 39 percent. President Biden’s immigration and border plan that expanded legal migration to the United States through humanitarian parole should take credit for this decline. Under Biden’s plan, up to 30,000 migrants from Venezuela, Cuba, Nicaragua, and Haiti (VCNH migrants) are allowed to enter the United States legally each month through humanitarian parole. As a result, more of them are waiting to come legally rather than attempting to cross illegally. In February 2023, the number of VCNH migrants encountered, found inadmissible by Customs and Border Protection (CBP), or apprehended by Border Patrol decreased by 84 percent compared to December 2022. The number of VCNH migrants showing up at the border fell from 91,344 in December to 22,084 in January and then further down to 14,381 in February (see Figure 1). The picture above is Alex’s Figure 1. Read the whole thing. (0 COMMENTS)

/ Learn More